First, enjoy some humor to warm you up to the topic.
I assume you already know the basics of the “SignalGate” scandal, as of March 27, 2025. If not, catch up to the present by checking out this detailed and, as far as I can tell, factually-accurate Wikipedia entry and this interview of Jeffrey Goldberg by The Bulwark’s Tim Miller.
Alright, if you know any MAGA or pro-Trump acquaintances and this topic happens to come up you are likely to hear some version of the defense used by CIA Director John Ratcliffe in his testimony to the Senate Intelligence Committee for using the Signal app to conduct a high-level discussion of military operations. He said that the Biden administration had issued guidance that allowed for the use of the Signal app. He failed to mention that the allowance applied to specific types of communication in specific circumstances, none of which applied to the discussion that Jeffrey Goldberg overheard. Some members of the administration and members of Congress have tried to back up Ratcliffe by saying that Signal was approved for classified communications during the Biden administration. This Snopes article refutes their claims. Read it for details and you can yell at me in the comments if you have good evidence that the Snopes article is incorrect.
In fact, up until the Trump regime took office, the Signal app was not allowed on any electronic equipment owned or leased by the federal government, nor were government employees permitted to use it for any government-related communications even on their own personal devices, if those communications included any classified information.
You may have heard that the Signal app, like Whatsapp or Telegram, will encrypt messages sent between devices. That way, a third party who happens to intercept the messages in transit can’t read them. All well and good, as far as that goes. Even better, Signal stores messages on your device in an encrypted database and the encryption key needed to decrypt the local messages is kept in your device’s keychain app. If you’re smart, you protected that keychain with a strong PIN, passphrase, or face or fingerprint ID. Unless you unlock your keychain and use the Signal app’s encryption key to decrypt the messages in the database, they are unreadable by humans.
That sure sounds secure, so what’s all the fuss from these “scaredy-cat libtards?” The big problem here is the overall security of the devices running Signal. Many (most?) of the members of the group who participated in the “SignalGate” group chat were running Signal on their personal cell phones. Those phones would be using some version of either Apple’s iOS operating system or some potentially customized version of Google’s Android operating system. These operating systems are designed for general use by the public, which means that the developers write in fewer security protections to make the devices easier to use. Most people wouldn’t put up with the many obstacles to ease of use that a tightly-secured operating system requires. While iOS and Android both have security features meant to protect users from easy and common security compromises, they are not secure enough to resist every attack highly-skilled hackers can throw at them.
Some of these hackers are members of private hacking groups, like “Anonymous.” Others are employees of government agencies, such as the NSA or Russia’s GRU. These groups are dedicated and in many cases have vast resources to investigate and exploit vulnerabilities in products like iOS and Android. There’s the classic fake tech support email or phone call. The “tech support” representative informs the user that a piece of malware has been discovered on their device and asks the user to install a piece of security software to clean up the malware or asks for a remote support session or asks the user for their login credentials. Once the user agrees the hackers have a foot in the door and can start making changes to the device that allow them to steal or change information on the device.
Then there is the discovery and exploitation of “zero-day” vulnerabilities. A “zero-day” vulnerability is a bug in the operating system that compromises the device’s security and that nobody knows about except the group of people who discovered it. There are thousands of professional and hobbyist security researchers who probe operating systems and applications for security vulnerabilities, and the vast majority of these are reported to the developers of the operating systems and applications so they can be fixed. That’s why the general public is encouraged to update their operating systems and applications regularly.
Some hacker groups, especially those employed by governments, will purposely not disclose to anyone else certain types of security vulnerabilities they discover. They are especially interested in vulnerabilities that basically overthrow the entire security architecture of the operating system or application and allow the hackers to steal data or take control of the device without the end user ever knowing it happened. In the case of the Signal application, the hackers would be able to access the device remotely, gain access to the Signal database encryption key when the user types in their PIN or shows their face to the camera to open the Signal database, and read all the user’s Signal messages, contacts, etc. while the user happily goes about chatting with their Signal contacts.
When one of these entities discovers such a vulnerability, doesn’t disclose it to anyone else, develops software to exploit it and then attacks devices using that software, we call that a “zero-day” attack. One of the most well-known pieces of software used to exploit cell phone vulnerabilities is Pegasus, a product of the Israeli firm NSO Group Technologies. Government agencies likely have their own in-house software that can perform similar functions, but we wouldn’t know about those and may never learn.
Once the organization who maintains the operating system or application that was exploited by this zero-day attack learns about the attack, figures out a fix and puts out updated software, the attack is no longer a zero-day attack. Trouble is, people using the devices vulnerable to this attack have to update the operating system or application on their devices to be protected. So let me ask you, when was the last time you updated iOS or Android or any of the applications on your cell phone? Wait, you don’t even know how to do that? Now you see why the government refused to allow Signal to be installed on its devices and told employees not to use Signal to transmit any classified information.
The most recent versions of iOS and Android are also vulnerable to exploits. How do I know that? Simple. Every operating system ever used in production by the general public has had vulnerabilities. Every single one. Have some hacker groups already discovered vulnerabilities in the current versions of iOS and Android that nobody else knows about? Most likely.
So, the members of this SignalGate group chat have been downplaying the classification level of the information shared by Pete Hegseth and denying that their use of Signal is against current government policy, and denying that they used Signal while in hostile territory, as if they had to be in Russia or China in order for foreign government hackers to read their Signal messages. Besides, some of them have said, the attack against the Houthis was successful, so what harm was done to US security?
This is all extremely bad. It means that not only have they been using Signal for some time already, but also that they have no intention to stop using it on their personal devices. Nor have they issued any public reassurances about the security protections they have applied to their personal devices, which means they don’t intend to do anything about that either. There is dedicated third-party software that can be installed on iOS and Android devices that offers some protection against these types of vulnerabilities. Is any of that software installed on the personal devices used by the parties in this group chat? None of them has offered any specifics, most likely because the answer is “no.”
Worse, they are apparently either too stupid or too arrogant to realize that since this information has become public, hackers of all types will be redoubling efforts to exploit their personal cell phones, assuming hackers haven’t done it already. Again, government hackers especially are not interested in letting their victims know that their devices have been compromised. If Russian agents, for example, had already gained access to one or more of the cell phones used during this chat, they probably wouldn’t have come to the aid of the Houthis. Why would they give the US government a reason to suspect a security compromise by saving the Houthis? They’d rather reap the future benefits of an open invitation to top-level chats about US military action (or non-action) in Europe.
In short, this situation is a security nightmare. By continuing these practices our top-level government officials are putting our entire country at risk.
In the previous post in this series I presented two models of a farm economy that were widely deployed in the British colonies of North America. In this post we will go over how government action affected the use of both models from the first decades of our country’s independence until the New Deal era just prior to World War II. This review will provide us with some understanding of the problems faced by earlier generations of farmers. That background will make it easier to understand how the American agricultural economy has become a plaything of the wealthy in more recent times.
After our country gained independence, restrictions on expansion westward imposed by the British government were removed. Again, I won’t dwell on the shameful history of our treatment of native Americans. Our focus here is on how government policies shaped which model of rural economy dominated as the country expanded. For more details on the changes in farm policy I will summarizing here, check out this document.
At first, federal policy favored selling newly-seized federal lands in the west to private parties at high prices. Southern politicians favored one goal of this policy, namely the spread of the plantation model. And, in fact, in the south the plantation model continued to expand westward. Wealthy planters could afford to buy large tracts of land. It was cheaper for them to move their plantations westward than to try replenishing the soils they had exhausted by repeatedly planting the same one or two crops they had been growing on their existing plots. The invention of the cotton gin opened a new market for cotton, which happened to grow wonderfully across large sections of the south. This also encouraged the spread of the plantation model, since the intense labor needed to harvest cotton could be obtained cheaply by using slaves.
Over the course of the early 19th century federal policy was repeatedly modified to promote the spread of the yeoman farmer model. Finally, the Homestead Act of 1864, passed during the Civil War when the southern states were not actively involved in US federal policy, settled the issue decisively in favor of the yeoman farm model for newly-settled lands in the mid-western and western US. As a result, by the end of the 19th century the vast majority of agriculture in America was carried out by small farmers. It should be pointed out that this act, and a couple of follow-up acts in the decade of the 1900s led to many new farms in the great plains, many new farmers, and the loss of huge tracts of native prairie land to agriculture. This led to some unforeseen consequences in later decades.
The American economy as a whole was transformed by the Civil War. Manufacturing, finance, and transportation industries exploded in size and economic power. As one might expect from our discussion of the unique vulnerabilities of rural communities, small farms were targeted for exploitation by some of these large businesses. For example, the railroad and riverboat barons raised shipping fees to the point that farmers found it difficult to afford shipping their products to market via rail or boat. Farm communities pressured their federal representatives to give them relief from these monopolies. This is one reason the Sherman Anti-Trust Act of 1890 was passed by Congress.
It would be a mistake to think that these major changer eliminated the plantation model altogether. Instead, via a series of maneuvers powerful landowners in the former Confederate states were able to re-establish the plantation model. First, they were able to break down the Reconstruction Era promise made to former slave owners that they would be able to establish small farms of their own. The famous “40 acres and a mule” policy was weakened and ignored to the extent that the majority of former slaves and their descendants who worked in agriculture in the southern states were either tenant farmers or farm laborers on land rented from the great plantation owners or their descendants.
Family farms did relatively well in the first two decades of the 20th century. As mentioned above, both the number of family farms and the average income of farm owners increased during these two decades. At first this was a result of several factors. Both federal and state government designed policies to protect farmers from exploitation by monopolists, ease their ability to obtain loans, and obtain information on improved farming and marketing techniques. The rise of farm cooperatives and organizations helped farmers pool their power and obtain better prices for their products. Organizations such as the Grange had been lobbying for the interests of family farmers to governments at all levels since its founding after the Civil War and the collective result of these efforts was also bearing fruit (sorry for the pun!) at this time.
When World War I broke out in 1914 European farm output dropped. Many American farmers, who were already doing relatively well, responded by quickly increasing production. During the war years American farmers prospered. The war ended in 1918, and by 1920 European agriculture was well on the way to recovery from the devastation of the war. As their production went up, the need for imports from America declined. American farmers who had rushed to increase production could not find another market for much of the crop they had produced. As a result, the price of agricultural products dropped. Farmers who had taken out loans to pay for lands they had bought to grow more crops or to buy seed and equipment were no longer able to make enough money to keep up with loan payments.
The federal government made some attempts to address farmers’ concerns in the 1920s but they didn’t lead to significant improvements for most farmers. Then twin disasters struck between 1929 and 1935. The Great Depression caused prices for agricultural products to drop precipitously, leaving many more farmers unable to make loan payments. Many farmers responded at first by trying to increase yields, but that just pushed prices down even further. Starting in 1931 a multi-year drought struck the mid-west. Crops failed. Many of the newer farm families were relatively inexperienced with drought conditions and had not developed strategies to deal with them. As a result, millions of acres of land were left bare. High winds carried off topsoil in dust storms. With their farms ruined, many farm families had little choice but to abandon their homes and move. All told, about 2.5 million people migrated out of the great plains states due to economic hardship during the 1930s.
The New Deal program initiated by the FDR administration included several measures addressing agricultural issues specifically. These measures altered the economics of farming fundamentally and laid the legal parameters for the recovery of American agriculture that took place starting in the 1940s.
The primary piece of legislation included in FDR’s New Deal for agriculture was the Agricultural Adjustment Act of 1933. This law, with some follow-up legislation in 1934 and 1935, set up a subsidy system for production of major agricultural commodities: wheat, corn (maize), hogs, cotton, tobacco, rice, milk, rye, flax, barley, grain sorghum, cattle, peanuts, sugar beets, sugar cane, and potatoes. Farmers were encouraged to work with the newly-formed federal agency, the Agricultural Adjustment Administration, to arrive at a level of production that would enable the farmer to receive a price for their produce as close as possible to the target price fixed by the law. The law specified that the target price would be the price for the produce in the years 1910-1914, when prices for farm products were high enough for most farmers to do well financially. If the farmer was forced to sell her produce below the target price the federal government paid the farmer a subsidy to bring her total receipts up to what they would have been if she had been paid the target price.
This law stabilized agricultural markets and saved many farmers from going bankrupt and many farms from foreclosure. The law was drafted largely based on the yeoman farm model, where the owner of the farm was also the person working the land. The federal agency worked directly with landowners, not farm laborers or tenant farmers. In a sharecropping situation, the federal government reimbursed the landowner if the price of the produce sold by tenant farmers using that land did not meet the target price. The law included provisions to ensure that for any subsidies awarded to landowners, appropriate percentages would be shared with tenant farmers or laborers who had worked the land. Southern lawmakers were able to weaken the subsidy sharing provisions and some agency employees overseeing the program in southern states purposely failed to enforce the provisions. As a result, tenant farmers in the south were largely driven out of business in the following decades.
The Supreme Court overthrew the Agricultural Adjustment Act in 1936 but the FDR administration was able to pass modified legislation tin 1938 hat passed muster with the Supreme Court and continued the subsidies. Congress also included in this legislation provisions to help mid-west farmers recover from the dust bowl devastation and change farming practices to protect and preserve topsoil.
The sum total of the changes brought about by the New Deal brought many American farmers teetering on the edge of bankruptcy and desperation into relative prosperity. In other cases, e.g. the “Okies” who migrated from the midwest to California to escape the Dust Bowl or the southern tenant farmers we mentioned above, the New Deal programs were not enough to save them from impoverishment. As a whole, however, the use of the plantation model was greatly reduced. Most farms remained of moderate size and operated on the yeoman model.
After World War II this situation changed drastically. What happened to the farm economy then and what it did to rural communities will be the topic of our next post.
For this fifth post in my “If You Can Keep It” series we will continue our focus on the economic fortunes of rural Americans. So much has changed in this year’s presidential election since my last post in this series, that I delayed this post until the changes had shaken out. We now have new Democratic candidates, the major party conventions have past, a long-awaited presidential debate has taken place, and in general, the presidential election landscape has been turned upside down.
It’s worth reminding you that the focus of this series is on the long-term effects of policies promoted by different interest groups in our country. What has happened to rural America is not an exception but just one part of a process that started several decades ago and extends across all sectors of our economy and society. The Biden administration and its allies on congress have, for the first time in decades, taken some critical steps to fix the structural problems in our society caused or made worse by pro-corporate government policies. The next congress and administration could continue fixing this but it’s likely that progress will be uneven and may require citizens to put additional pressure on whoever ends up in office next year before changes take place. The better we understand how we got into this pickle and what can be done to fix it, the likelier it will be that we choose the right people to govern us.
Given that there is less than a month left before this year’s election, I’ll give you my opinion on how to vote. I start from the fact that there are stark differences between the two major parties’ approaches to economic matters, including how to deal with the unique problems faced by citizens in rural America. The Republican party has clearly prioritized the needs and desires of the wealthiest citizens and left the rest of us to pay the price. This has been true since the Reagan revolution and the recent ascendance of the MAGA movement has not changed it much. Trump and his lackeys talk a better game than some of the older economic conservatives, e.g., Newt Gingrich, but the actual policies they support and propose lead to the same results. Hence, the Gingriches, Thiels, Musks, and other wealthy Republican backers largely still support Trump and other MAGA candidates. Most of the federal and state policies that have cost rural Americans the most were enacted under Republican administrations, most of the laws enabling these policies were passed by state and federal legislatures in which Republicans were the majority.
These facts do not excuse the Democratic party. Many Democrats, including some representing rural communities, having bought into mistaken economic theories, cooperated with Republicans in passing harmful laws. Some members of Democratic presidential administrations, especially in the Carter, Clinton, and Obama administrations were also foolishly overawed by the economic theories of market fundamentalists and ran agencies in charge of federal policy toward rural communities in a way that favored the wealthy.
If you believe our government is handling the problems of rural America poorly, your best bet is to vote for Democrats in this election. If this election yields both a Trump administration and a Republican congress, rural Americans will suffer for it. It’s highly ironic that some of the strongest support for the MAGA movement comes from rural Americans. There are many reasons for this, but it remains a fact that the policies that Republicans favored in the past and are favoring now will not help rural Americans. There is at least hope for improvement if a Harris administration and Democratic congress take over, but only hope. Over the last several years large numbers of economically-conservative citizens have started supporting Democratic candidates, mostly due to fear of/disgust toward the MAGA movement in the Republican party. These folks will be bending the ears of Harris administration members and congressional Democrats to moderate or gut new policies designed to fix structural economic problems that impoverish rural communities. This goes for every other area of economic policy as well. What ordinary citizens communicate to their representatives after the election may matter as much or even more than which representatives we elect.
In the previous post in this series I gave you some background economic context, namely that people who live in rural areas face some unique challenges that make them especially vulnerable to the twin economic evils of monopoly and monopsony. If you aren’t familiar with that background you should probably read that post first. This post will start a brief history lesson that will take us through the next few posts.
What I’m about to describe is a vast oversimplification, that despite regional variations still holds true. As Europeans began to settle in the British colonies of North America, rural farming communities organized themselves following one of two models, the plantation or the yeoman farm.
Plantations were designed to produce large quantities of one or two cash crops, such as tobacco, rice, or cotton for sale on the export market. Typical plantation owners farmed hundreds or even thousands of acres and relied on slave labor to do the bulk of the work. A planter needed access to a lot of money to afford the land, the slaves, and the materials needed to start and maintain a farm this large. They obtained this money via inheritance from rich relatives who were wealthy merchants or royalty in Europe, generous land grants from the government, bank loans, and profits from the sale of the prior harvests of these highly-valued crops. This model resulted in a highly-stratified society, with a few relatively wealthy planters surrounded by a far larger number of impoverished slaves, indentured servants and free citizens who were trapped in low-wage occupations with no realistic ability to obtain enough capital to improve their lot in life. In this arrangement, the members of the planter class enjoyed far more freedom than everyone else. It should also be noted that in the regions where plantations dominated, there were relatively few urban centers or even small towns. Most planters depended on their slaves to provide many of the adjunct services that farmers in other areas would obtain from specialists in nearby towns or cities, e.g. smithies, carpentry, leather-working, tailoring, etc. This situation prevailed in the southern colonies.
Yeoman farms were smaller, rarely larger than 250 acres of actively-farmed land, mainly because the owners relied on members of their own immediate or extended family to perform most of the work. These farms also tended to be more complex operations, because they balanced growing multiple types of crops with animal husbandry. Where this model became dominant, villages, small towns and cities appeared in greater numbers to accommodate the artisans, traders, and professionals needed to support and supply the surrounding farm communities. Cumulative wealth was more equally distributed in regions where this model dominated. It prevailed in the northern colonies but was found in certain regions of the southern colonies as well. Small farms sprang up in the colonies wherever large numbers of European settlers of humble means settled. Most of the northern colonies started out this way.
In the next post we will review the first 150 years of the agricultural history of the United States.
This fourth post in my “If You Can Keep It” series appears at the end of a week that included the first debate in the 2024 presidential election, a debate that has many of those 50 million Americans who watched it wishing that there were some other viable candidate besides the two that have been chosen by the two major parties. It also included a series of supreme court rulings that will require major changes in the way our government functions and could lead to our federal government changing from a democratic republic to a dictatorship.
Those of you who have been following this series so far may decide to spend your time focusing on these other issues for now. I understand that completely. It seems to me as well that a five-alarm fire has broken out in our society. As scary as some recent events may be, there isn’t much many of us can do about them right now. Also, understanding the context and background events that led to the rise of Donald Trump and Joe Biden and the recent supreme court decisions can help you take a longer view and make better decisions about what you ask of your government representatives and who you vote for come November. The goal of this series is to provide that critical background. I hope you will stick around, and if not, that you will come back later in the year (preferably by September) to catch up on the posts you have missed and share them with others, especially people you know who may be undecided or disenchanted about voting this November.
In the introduction I indicated that one current, fundamental problem of American society is that the extremely wealthy have managed to reconfigure the economy and government policies to give them more freedom and take it away from everyone else. As Warren Buffett put it, “There’s class warfare, all right, but it’s my class, the rich class, that’s making war, and we’re winning.” One of the most obvious illustrations is the accelerating decline of rural American life. Most of the people who will read this series likely don’t know much about the vulnerabilities unique to rural and agricultural communities. Because it was so easy for corporate powers to exploit these vulnerabilities, it also makes it easier for me to illustrate trends that, with some variations, affect the rest of us.
My nuclear family has a personal stake in this issue. We have lived in or near farm communities for most of the last 30 years, including 18 years operating our own small horse farms. Reader, you have a stake in this issue as well, because, for better or worse, what happens in these communities affects what you eat every day, the kind of building in which you live, and how you get around.
One of the major virtues needed to thrive in a rural community is self-reliance. Since you have few others nearby you can rely on to supply your needs, you need to learn how to fend for yourself in many difficult circumstances. This principle broadens out as people in a rural area band together. A family living far away from others needs to be able to supply its own needs by relying only on those in the family. A small community group living far away from others needs to do the same. In fact, we are told that human beings lived in small, relatively isolated groups like this for most of human history.
Unfortunately, living with only a small, relatively-isolated group of human beings to rely on is a risky proposition. Not that others in the group are unreliable or malicious, it’s rather that there are too many potential catastrophic events that a small, isolated group doesn’t have the resources to protect one another from. For that reason, most people living in rural areas have depended on resources provided by a larger society for at least some of their critical needs.
Relying on a larger society’s resources to support a rural lifestyle comes at a cost. Put yourself for a moment on a farm several miles outside a village in central Kansas, Nebraska, Iowa, or North or South Dakota. Since you are relatively far away from the larger society, making contact with it is expensive and time-consuming. Not many from a more urbanized environment will be willing to invest the time and money to bring the resources you need. Those who do will aim to be your sole provider. If they can pull that off, they can demand a higher price in exchange for the resources they provide. The technical term for this type of arrangement is a monopoly. or single-seller situation.
Conversely, in order to pay for the resources coming from the outside, you have to trade something you’ve gathered, grown or made. Those who are willing to spend the time and money to buy the items you have for trade will aim to be the sole purchaser. If they can pull that off, they can pay you a much lower price than you would be willing to accept if there were someone else you could sell it to instead. The technical term for this type of arrangement is a monopsony or single-buyer situation.
American government has always been aware of the potential for exploitation of rural citizens by outside entrepeneurs. For example, when the country was very young cross-country travel was extremely difficult. Not having the funds to build and maintain roads, governments relied on private investment for road-building. In order to recoup their investments, the companies that built these roads charged tolls. When the state of Pennsylvania contracted with a private company to build a turnpike between Philadelphia and Lancaster, PA, they set toll prices to prevent the company from charging excessive tolls, since the turnpike was by far the fastest and easiest way to get into the interior of the state.
The twin curses of monopoly and monopsony have frequently plagued the rural inhabitants of North America for hundreds of years. Here is a brief list of examples in roughly historical order:
the Sioux tribe dominating trade along the Missouri river in the late 18th century. (I bring up this example to illustrate that this is not just a problem with “capitalism.” In no way do I mean to excuse the controversial and often shameful history of European settlement in North America.)
rural inhabitants (any many urbanites as well) living in the later 1800s who needed to travel or send or receive freight over long distances often had little choice but to use one of several regional railroad monopolies, such as the Central Pacific, the Pennsylvania or the New York railroad.
Let’s pause at this point to reflect on the railroads. Railroads are a prime example of what is commonly called a natural monopoly. It costs a lot to build track and trains by design can only run on track. If you want trains running in both directions along the same route, you either have to build two tracks or include frequent and long sidings that allow one train to get out of the way temporarily for another train coming down the same track in the opposite direction. The engines, cars, and fuel needed to operate a train are all very expensive. For these reasons, it is impractical for several different outfits to provide similar train service to the same group of customers. Instead, a single railroad company typically built out all the rail lines that served a specific community or region, depending on the size of the railroad company.
In the late 19th century our federal and state governments by and large failed to follow the example of the state of Pennsylvania’s contract with the turnpike company by regulating the rates the railroads could charge their customers. Railroads were allowed to charge customers whatever they could get away with. Furthermore, it became customary for railroads to provide special rebates to certain customers. Most of us are used to this type of differential, “buy-in-bulk” pricing. In the late 19th century, however, the practice came with some shady extras. For example, a railroad company would make a private agreement with, say John D. Rockefeller’s Standard Oil Company, to ship the oil at a huge discount. In exchange, Standard Oil would ship enough oil to occupy an entire train’s worth of freight and handle all the loading and unloading. This arrangement saved the railroad enough to offer the discount without cutting into its own profits. But Standard Oil added a couple of other provisos. The railroad agreed to either a.) not offer the same discounts to other oil producers or b.) not ship oil for other oil producers at all. (By the way, Standard Oil became a monopoly in the oil distribution industry and was broken up by the federal government in 1911 for violating the 1890 Sherman Anti-Trust Act.)
The Theodore Roosevelt administration brought the railroad monopolies to heal with the help of Congress when it passed the Hepburn Rate Bill in 1906. This bill outlawed the type of discriminatory rebates discussed above and set minimum and maximum shipping rates. President Roosevelt made several public speeches in advance of the votes on this bill, arguing that the government needed to step in to regulate the railroad monopolies because left on their own they would continue to reward large corporate customers with special deals and punish small businesses like farmers and consumers with higher prices simply because these customers had no other option. You can read more about Roosevelt’s reasoning in support of federal regulation of railroad shipping rates here.
In the next few posts we will examine how large corporate interests gained monopsony power over farmers and what has happened as a result. We will also explore how Walmart built its retail empire in part by impoverishing small towns. Finally, we will examine how government’s corporate-friendly approach to healthcare has led to the disappearance of healthcare providers in wide swaths of rural America.
As I promised in my previous post, this post will examine the role employee non-compete agreements — and the even more nefarious and hidden phenomenon known as no-poach agreements — play in the political assignment of civic freedoms.
Imagine it is 2013 and you are looking for a part-time job in retail food service to supplement your income. When you were a teenager you had worked in a local grill and despite the relatively low wages you had appreciated the schedule flexibility and the companionship of your co-workers. You figure that you could handle the responsibilities of a part-time shift manager at a place like that and earn enough to meet your budget goals.
Over the course of the succeeding decades most of the local fast-food joints have been put out of business by competition from national chains that now dominate in the nearby commercial district. “How much different can it be to work in a chain restaurant?” you figure, and submit applications to a number of them.
Eventually, you score an interview at the local Jimmy John’s sandwich shop. The hiring manager is impressed by your maturity and offers you a job with the encouragement that after learning the shop’s procedures you could easily advance to a part-time junior manager. “That’s the ticket!” you say to yourself and decide to take the job.
You leave the shop with a sinking feeling after the hiring manager wishes you a cheery, “Good luck!” Over the course of the next few weeks you get similar offers from an Arby’s, a Subway, a Panera Bread, and a Jersey Mike’s. Guess what, they all had similar language in their employment contracts! You finally luck out at the local McDonald’s. This time the interviewer hasn’t painted such a rosy picture of an up and coming management position, but between relief that the employment contract doesn’t include a non-compete clause and knowledge that there are plenty of McDonald’s restaurants with potential management openings within driving distance of your house, you take the job.
As expected you learn the operations of the business quickly and within a few months receive multiple, albeit small, pay-raises. Anticipating that you will soon be a viable candidate for a management post you make a habit of watching the online management training videos offered by McDonald’s and practicing as much of their recommendations as possible for a team member.
Your McDonald’s has a bulletin board in the break room with a section on local McDonald’s job postings. Unfortunately for you, none of the jobs posted on that board are management-level. You’ve known since you started that a lot more McDonald’s job openings in your community are posted on McDonald’s website than show up on the bulletin board, probably because there just isn’t room to post them all.
You search the job openings on McDonald’s website for any part-time shift manager openings nearby and sure enough, a couple of McDonald’s in other parts of town have openings for a part-time manager, so you apply. After not hearing back about either position, two weeks later you make a follow-up phone call to the phone number listed on the application website to find out where you stand. You notice that both openings listed the same phone number. A human resources rep answers the phone. Here is the brief conversation:
“Based on your prior experience you are not a suitable candidate for either position. Thank you very much for applying.”
“What could I do to improve my chances for the next opening?”
“Your best bet is to apply for the positions posted on your local job board. Each McDonald’s franchise has its own hiring criteria and the franchise owners prefer to promote from within their own staff.”
You knew the franchise owners were your real employer, not McDonald’s corporation. The McDonald’s application website makes that clear as day. Each franchise makes its own personnel decisions. You now realize that the two locations with openings belong to a different franchise from the one that runs your location. You also realize that all the job openings posted on the local job board at your location are at locations run by the same franchise that runs your location. You are still puzzled by the human resources rep’s advice. It’s not like each franchise is allowed to have its own management philosophy. McDonald’s insists that managers at all facilities using its brand train for the same attitudes, procedures, and skills. Also, a preference for promoting from within isn’t the same as a law, but it is pretty obvious from their answer that trying to get hired for a position in that franchise was likely to fail. Yes indeed, time for another “WTF?”
Clearly, your options for turning this side-hustle work into a promising addition to the family’s income have narrowed considerably. I’ll bet you feel, not free, but trapped. What is going on here?
You have become a victim of two different schemes the retail fast-food industry has employed to reduce costs by suppressing the wages of their employees. You were confronted directly with the employee non-compete clause in the employment agreements you were asked to sign. The use of these non-compete clauses spread throughout the industry over the last few decades and only a few companies, such as McDonald’s and Chick-Fil-A, never used them.
But employee non-competes are just the tip of the iceberg. Franchisees and the owners of national fast-food chains have a common interest in keeping wage costs low. Enter the “no-poach” clause in franchise agreements. When someone bought a McDonald’s franchise, they agreed that they would not hire anyone employed by a McDonald’s run by a different franchisee. That would prevent a spiraling wage war between different franchisees operating in the same market. Nobody told you about this arrangement between McDonald’s and its franchisees. One reason is that they don’t have to. There are many other reasons, all colored green. Hence the person on the other end of that phone call giving you BS about why you weren’t suitable for the management positions. There was only one reason you weren’t suitable: you already worked for another McDonald’s franchise!
So, where did such arrangements come from? It’s not anything new. In the old economic arrangements that preceded western capitalism slaves, land-bound peasants, and Russian serfs were not free to take their labor elsewhere. Mercantilism and its successor, capitalism, allowed for more mobility for workers from backgrounds of modest means to improve their economic circumstances. In a later post I will provide much more detail on the improvements and dangers for most people in the rise of capitalism.
By the time the Unites States gained independence the use of non-competes here was pretty rare, given that the English legal tradition of refusing to enforce them came over with the colonists. In the ensuing decades the country was just beginning the transition from an economy largely based on agriculture to early-stage capitalism. The new circumstances employers and laborers found themselves in prompted US state governments to reconsider their stance on “restraints on trade,” that is various contracts and arrangements that limited what could be sold or bought or who could work for whom. Non-compete and no-poach agreements are examples of “restraints on trade.”
“Wait,” you say, “why didn’t the US government regulate this?” OK, let’s revisit our high school civics and/or American history classes. As prescribed in the constitution, government in the USA operates under the federal system. The US constitution defines the limited roles and powers of the national government and leaves large areas of government action to be handled by the individual states. Employment contract laws fall within the jurisdiction of the states. State laws have varied in how they handle non-compete clauses ever since the country was established. A few states, e.g. California, have had near-absolute bans on employee non-compete contracts. Many more have allowed for them but under limited circumstances, with some states tending to enforce them in more cases than other states. Much of this variation arose in the course of the 19th century as states adjusted their contract laws to deal with the increasingly complicated relationship between growing companies and their employees.
In a later post we will examing the way the federal government has enforced this Act in the last 130 years to prevent or break up monopolies. The Act also made it illegal for businesses to make agreements with each other that would prevent other competitors from damaging the economic power of the businesses included in the agreement. A “no-poach” agreement is a prime example of this type of illegal activity.
In the 20th century non-compete clauses became an increasingly common feature in employment contracts for senior executives, sales managers and their teams, and highly-trained engineers, analysts, and technical workers. This makes some sense. An employee who has intimate knowledge of a company’s proprietary trade secrets and operational procedures, some or all of which make it an effective competitor in the market, could damage the company’s prospects if they take that proprietary information to a competitor or start their own company in the same business. Likewise, someone with intimate knowledge of a company’s clients could wean them away after departing to work for a competitor. Legally enforceable non-compete agreements are a relatively easy way to discourage employees from this type of behavior.
By the mid-2010s non-compete and no-poach agreements had become widespread in sectors of the economy that employed large numbers of low-wage workers, e.g. hospitality and retail sales. I was unable to find much research on how these types of agreements spread to different sectors of the economy over the last several decades. This is partly due to the difficulties in obtaining good data on these practices. The federal Bureau of Labor Statistics, for example, didn’t even start collecting data on the prevalence of non-compete agreements until 2017 and that decision was motivated in part by a 2014 New York Times report by Steven Greenhouse on the effects of the burgeoning use of non-compete agreements among low-wage workers in Massachusetts.
Why did the companies come to agreements with the states rather than trying to fight them in court? Simple, no-poach agreements are clearly in violation of the Sherman Anti-Trust Act. The companies’ legal teams knew they had no leg to stand on and told senior executives so.
If no-poach agreements are clearly illegal, why did companies use them in the first place? The answer to this question is at least partly tied in with the answer to the question, “Why do companies include non-compete clauses in their contracts with low-wage employees?” Put simply, companies do this because they can get away with it. In both cases companies recognize the vast power advantage they have over low-wage employees and use these agreements to take away some more of the workers’ bargaining power. The workers don’t know about the no-poach agreements, so they won’t complain about them, and they don’t have the resources to fight a legal battle if they try to violate the non-compete agreement. The workers are cowed into staying with their current employer and accepting lower wages and significantly fewer opportunities to advance their careers.
The top executives and major shareholders of retail food service chains realized that if non-compete and no-poach agreements became the standard practice across the industry it would pretty much lock their front-line workers into their current positions or at most to promotions within the same franchise. Freezing worker mobility would not only reduce the employee turnover rate but it would also make it much easier for franchisees to turn down worker requests for more pay. These are the same people who worked hard to keep both the federal and state governments from raising the minimum wage. They benefited greatly from having society at large subsidize their workforce via programs such as SNAP, LIHEAP, and community food banks. They could retain their desperate, stressed workforce without increasing wages, let tax revenues and charity cover the difference, and have shareholders pocket the money that otherwise would have gone to workers.
This scheme works great when there is an excess of workers, but it creates real problems for franchisees when unemployment rates drop very low, as has been the case for a number of years now. When retail workers with experience can’t move between franchises or employers and there are not enough people on the sidelines available as new hires, positions go unfilled, forcing locations to reduce hours and/or services. Workers become more stressed and either leave or engage in theft or sabotage, and customers become irritated. For example, I had been a big fan of a local Wendy’s as a fast-food option due to the salad options on their menu, but after they cut back dine-in hours to a minimum and removed free wifi at all the Syracuse locations I visited, I stopped going altogether, haven’t been back for four years and don’t plan on eating at a Wendy’s ever again.
One possible solution to this problem would be to raise the number of unemployed people. These newly-unemployed would become potential candidates for the the open positions and sales would drop, easing the pressure to hire additional workers to provide full services. In the recent history of the US Federal Reserve they have resorted to raising interest rates when the economy becomes “overheated,” expecting that the economy will slow down. This usually results in people losing their jobs, which would “solve” the worker problem for our franchisees. I’ll have much more to say about how government action can best deal with situations like this in a later post.
The other obvious solution would be to start raising worker pay to retain and attract workers, but many franchises were already squeezed by increased costs for supplies, insurance, rent, etc, the fixed fees they were required to pay to the corporation, and the risk to revenue posed by raising prices. Some franchises raised both pay and prices. Some raised pay and took the hit to their own profits. Some decided to not raise pay and live with the consequences. Regardless of the franchisees decisions, the corporations have not adjusted their fee structures to help out franchisees.
Since economists began systematically researching the effects of these agreements on low-wage workers evidence has accumulated that worker pay is about 4-5% lower than it would be otherwise in states that enforce these agreements. That evidence has led some state legislatures to pass laws restricting or outlawing the use of these agreements. The federal National Labor Relations Board issued a new rule in 2023 that treats corporations and their franchisees as joint employers, now both subject to unfair labor practice laws. By the way, this action reverses a decision in 2020 under the Trump administration that basically freed corporations from any liability for unfair labor practices committed by their franchisees. (That little piece of information is meant for those of you who believe that “both sides do it.”) Regulators at the Federal Trade Commission have also issued a rule banning non-competes nationwide for almost all employees. This rule hasn’t gone into effect yet pending the outcome of lawsuits filed by the US Chamber of Commerce and others. Whatever ends up happening to that specific rule, it is clear that more and more governments in our country regard the use of non-compete and no-poach agreements against low-wage workers as an unjust deprivation of workers’ freedom.
In subsequent posts we will explore several other methods corporations, their major shareholders and their political and academics allies have used to enrich themselves at the expense of most of the rest of us. Some of these other methods have hurt working and middle-class Americans much worse than the use of non-compete and no-poach agreements. We will find people defending these methods in the name of preserving and protecting freedom. I hope that this post will help you be more critical of these defenders when they trot out “freedom” language.
After his parents file an application for an Extreme Risk Protection Order against him, a judge approves it, and the police confiscate the firearms and ammunition at his home, a young man complains about the confiscation of his guns on social media and obtains help from a second amendment activist organization to file a lawsuit contesting the constitutionality of the red-flag law used to execute the Extreme Risk Protection Order.
A woman with an ectopic pregnancy, after failing to find a provider that would perform an abortion, appeals to the supreme court of her state and is denied legal permission to have an abortion. She chooses to travel out of state to have the abortion.
Ranchers vie with native American tribes and environmentalists over the designation of a national monument in northern Arizona. Ranchers may lose the freedom to graze cattle on those public lands if it is declared a national monument. The tribes have lost the freedom to protect sacred sites in that area and would like to reclaim it. Environmentalists want to prevent mining interests from polluting the area by mining uranium.
The FTC issues a rule to nullify employee non-compete agreements for almost all employees of American companies. The purpose is to grant employees greater freedom to seek better opportunities in the same industry. The US Chamber of Commerce sues to block enforcement of the new rule, claiming that it takes away from businesses the freedom to protect their intellectual property from theft by employees departing to competitors.
Did you notice how in each scenario above one person or group’s freedom impinges on another’s? Did you notice that in each case laws or rules enacted by government were used to expand or restrict some individual’s or group’s freedom? You may also find yourself rooting for one side or the other based on additional knowledge of the situation or your own opinion on similar issues.
The first two of these situations are composites of multiple, real, recent events. The last two are real events. In each case I’ve left out significant details that could change your own view about what freedoms are at stake and what approach to the situation could produce the best outcome. It is also true that in each of these situations the majority of the leaders in the Democratic and Republican party have an opposing view of the best way to resolve the issue. Finally, although in each situation the competing individuals or groups are all seeking to protect or expand some type or realm of freedom — which their advocates exploit to stir up outrage and anger against the opposing individuals or groups — it is also the case that the types of freedom at stake and the costs involved in gaining or losing their freedom differ for those involved.
Nearly every issue that will be addressed in this entire series has to do with someone’s loss or gain of freedom. It is incumbent on me as the author and you as the reader to weigh carefully the costs and benefits to all parties involved in the exercise or restriction of freedoms discussed in the posts to come, and not let any advocate’s cries of “liberty!” prejudice us against a solution that ends up doing the most good.
In the next post we’ll wrestle over the competing benefits and costs of employee non-complete agreements for employees and companies.
According to an old story a prominent Philadelphia host and correspondent of the political elites, Elizabeth Willing Powel, had Benjamin Franklin over to her house at the end of the constitutional convention of 1787 and asked him, “Well, doctor, what have we got, a republic or a monarchy?” He responded, “A republic, if you can keep it.”
This post is the first in a series exploring current threats to our democratic form of government and offering suggestions on how our society and each of us as individuals can preserve or recover freedoms that belong to all our citizens and restore and increase their well-being, aka “happiness,” that Thomas Jefferson declared in the Declaration of Independence was the “unalienable right” of all people.
Mostly you can expect posts on politics or economics, although there will also be forays into the sciences and my specialties, information technology and Christian belief. To encourage sharing links to the posts with friends, family, co-workers, etc, the posts will all be accessible to the general public, kept short, and refer to other resources for those who want to dig deeper. Based on my schedule and other commitments, I expect new posts to come out between every two to four weeks. The plan is to continue the series through the upcoming general election and beyond.
The intent of this series is to be as non-partisan as possible, although there will be obvious and perhaps not-so-obvious limits. So let’s get my own orientation out in the open first. I believe a representative democracy, aka, a (small “r”) republican form of government, with separation of powers and guarantees of rights for citizens is the safest form of government over the long term. I believe that a mixed economy provides the greatest benefit to the broadest range of participants in that economy. A mixed economy includes a free market for most goods and services with government regulations designed to limit concentration of economic power in any one sector or class and to protect the people at large from market failures.
I believe that an economy ought to regulated so that
it is relatively easy for someone who is contributing something of value to society to achieve a stable, long, and healthy life for themselves and their loved ones
those who cannot support themselves are not left to slip into poverty and desperation
those who have the ability and circumstances to achieve greater wealth should find that as their wealth increases it also becomes increasingly difficult to accumulate more.
By the way, hat-tip to both Neil Gorsuch and NPR for the Ben Franklin quote included in the title of this series.
Here is a list of some of the topics I hope to cover, in no particular order:
what does “freedom” mean?
Project 2025: what it is and how it plans to reconfigure the federal government to become a permanent arm of a wealthy oligarchy
large numbers of wealthy people have been engaged in class warfare against the rest of American society
“Neo-liberalism:” what it is, how it became the favored framework for guiding government economic policy, and how it transferred trillions of dollars from most Americans to the wealthy.
how the manipulative actions of the leaders of the Federalist Society have led to the corruption of our federal and state judiciaries in favor of the wealthy
how corporate power has contributed to the dangerous delay in addressing climate change
how deregulation of monopolies has hurt most American workers
how failure to raise the minimum wage has hurt most American workers
how failure to fund public education has made what was easy for baby boomers almost impossible for Gen Z
how repeated tax cuts have hurt our government and economy
how under-investment in infrastructure has reduced our ability to compete in the global economy
how the increasing use of “dark money” has enabled small minorities of the wealthy and powerful to bend public opinion in favor of their preferred policies
“Surveillance Capitalism” and the “enshittification” of the internet
how deregulation of the banking industry led to the economic catastrophe of 2007-2009
why Libertarian approaches to government policy usually hurt most Americans
how the spread of employee non-compete agreements stole money from workers
how the government’s failure to update overtime rules stole money from workers
how drug companies have been able to drive up the costs of pharmaceuticals so drastically
why housing costs have risen so dramatically over the last several decades
why much pearl-clutching over federal entitlement spending is done to promote the interests of the wealthy
Our thirty-sixth year, I think. Some things never get old.
One of our more recent traditions is the Dolphin watch on the Thundercat. As usual, the ride was packed, but this year we had one special guest waiting with me and Philip at the dock.
At least the guest was quiet …
while it waited for our ride
See below to understand better why we keep doing this.
Erika and I like to walk on the beachfront early in the morning. We’ve done that every time we go. After the walk we stop to pick up bagels for breakfast. When we went with Erika’s parents they used to come with us and Philip came to when he was younger. Erika’s mom is too frail for that walk now and we let Philip choose walk or bike ride. This year he picked bike ride.
We hit the pool in the late morning. This year we had it to ourselves every morning.
In the afternoon we head to the beach. The last few years we’ve favored Philadelphia Ave. beach. It’s relatively easy to find parking there even when the beach is crowded. The water was cold this year, 67 degrees F according to the Cape May beach patrol, but once you get numb to it, who cares? Philip and I like the water, Erika likes to read in the shade.
Good old Charlie Brown isn’t the only one with a weak spot for lousy-looking Christmas trees. We are fortunate enough to own a small farm property, including several acres that were once used to grow Christmas trees. Most of the trees are still there, only now they are 30-50 feet high. Still, since we moved to Syracuse we’ve cut down one of the trees every Christmas season and used the top portion for our Christmas tree. This year was no different.
The process is simple. First, you go out and find the right type of tree with a promising top. Like this one:
A fraser fir, one of my personal favorites for a Christmas tree. From 40 ft down that top looks pretty full and balanced. Sure, it’s not trimmed to a perfect conical shape like the people who run tree farms for a living do for their customers, but it’s good enough for government work.
Next, we cut down the tree and lop off the top 9-10 feet for our Christmas tree. See how good it looks now!
OK, there are some issues, like the brown stuff in the middle and the gap in the branch spread about 2/3 of the way up, but it still looks like a Christmas tree.
We drag it to the house and I chop off the lowest branches to leave room for the trunk to sit in the tree stand. And then I realize my mistake. Those lowest branches hid a layer of unexpectedly short branches right above them. Withe lowest branches gone the tree suddenly takes on the shape of a 60 year-old man, like this guy:
How many of you allow a 60 year-old man to prance around your house clad only in his underwear? Neither do we (ha, I’m 62).
What to do? As I set the base of the tree in a water bucket I weighed my second thoughts. We have about 4 acres of firs and spruces; I could cut down a better one. But no, dammit! To leave this tree naked by the cold roadside for the township to pick up while we are inside celebrating with a better-looking tree seems unnecessarily cruel and self-indulgent. The tree didn’t ask to be cut down; it’s only fair that we use it. Well, actually my second thought was, do I really want to haul out the chainsaw and wander back under the trees in the half-dark and cut one down that may be worse? And so, after taking inspiration from my inner Linus and inner Dude we decorate the tree, yielding a festive treat for forgiving eyes.
Those of you with a tender conscience about trees may take comfort in learning that a nearby nursery took the rest of the branches from that tree to use in their annual wreath-making classes. The trunk will be cut up and used for firewood.
How many times in discussions of social problems have you heard people invoke some economic principle, law, or guideline to explain why their solution works and yours doesn’t? How many times have you done the same? Where do these ideas about economics come from? How reliable are they? What are these ideas anyway? Natural laws? Moral preferences? Generalizations based on past experience? A picture some smart guy drew on a napkin to illustrate a theory he cooked up minus any evidence (no, I’m not making this up)?
Maybe you took an economics course or two in college. How long ago was that? Maybe, like me, you never studied economics at all. Frankly, I grew tired of hearing people attempt to clinch their viewpoint on policy with some principle of economics that I either never heard of, did not understand or could not evaluate.
A little background. The vast majority of cases involve disputes with my former fellow reformed and Presbyterian colleagues and, after I left the pastorate and the evangelical fold, Ayn Rand acolytes. These people were all basically advocates of the “market fundamentalism” (Joseph Stiglitz’s term) of Ludwig Von Mises, Friedrich Hayek, and their ilk.
So, I decided to start educating myself. If you want to do the same, here is a quick list of internet resources.
And for those of you who object that my list so far is too left-wing, Russ Roberts
The Mises Institute. I’m posting this to cover the full range of opinion but not advocating for it. Ludwig Von Mises was a smart guy who made many correct observations about how economies work but also made some critical errors that subsequent research has corrected. Unfortunately, his followers are fundamentalists in the worst sense of the word. Please don’t add to their number.